In preparation for a lecture, I’ve been mulling over some books and papers on co-operation in human societies. One of my favourites is Paul Seabright’s [amazon_link id=”0691146462″ target=”_blank” ]The Company of Strangers[/amazon_link]. Another isĀ [amazon_link id=”0691151253″ target=”_blank” ]A Co-operative Species: Human Reciprocity and its Evolution[/amazon_link] by Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis. This latter book, published last year combines evolutionary theory and game theory to analyse reciprocity. As the authors point out, it is easy to see the benefits of co-operation among groups of humans, in our early history as now – but not so easy to see how co-operation evolved or is sustained, as the costs of reciprocity fall relatively heavily on individuals while the benefits are shared among the whole group.
The question of sustaining co-operation becomes all the more pressing. The problems we face are complicated and global, and will not be tackled without co-operation. Think about climate change, or the continuing economic crisis. The social and economic structures we have built depend on sustaining an almost miraculous level of co-operation – think about the global supply chains for many of the products we have come to depend on, or the fact that more than half of us now live in close contact in massive, cosmopolitan cities. Can the mutual trust and co-operation that has got us here be sustained?
Bowles and Gintis see this as a question about the “distinctive human capacity for institution-building and cultural transmission of learned behaviour.” (p197) They reference Elinor Ostrom’s work on the role of incentives and sanctions in a specific institutional framework in supporting contemporary co-operation. The authors conclude with a reasonable degree of optimism that the forces that made altruism and co-operation a competitive advantage in pre-historic times continue to operate – we are simply better off by co-operating. But, as they conclude, neither private market contracts nor government fiat have ever shaped the actual forms of co-operative economic activity. In a minor way, this was brought to mind by our Jubilee street party on Monday, an entirely self-organised phenomenon, repeated many times over, all around the country.
This kind of co-operation is a question of culture and institutions, which need to develop continually as our economies and societies change. To continue yesterday’s theme, what kind of culture and institutions will support a complex globalized economy facing multiple crises?
[amazon_image id=”0691151253″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and Its Evolution[/amazon_image]
I always think that the concept of co-operation starts with the idea of ‘ubuntu’ and then builds from there. Richard Sennett’s recent book “Together” is quite interesting on this idea too.
I hope you are of the view that the extreme view of the market as ubiquitous and yet apersonal is a nonsense: the market is fundamentally about people, and co-operation in all respects: its creation, the context in which it operates and so on.
Co-operation at its most basic, an acceptance of the need to share, if not always shared ideals, is the cement which glues modern economies together. It is when there isn’t the necessary co-operation to fashion solutions to economic problems that real economic problems exist.
I wonder where the Euro crisis fits into all this? I suspect that a desire to co-operate is up against it here, in that any co-operation between EU members seems to be about supporting a construct that no-one really believes in. And this lack of intrinsic belief is, in turn, weakening the desire to co-operate.
That’s a difficult question. Seems to me that there is support for the ideal of European co-operation still, but wholly inappropriate institutions to put it into practice. EU institutions have been even less responsive than national political institutions. But I’m not sure…. I’ve not read that Sennett book, must give it a go.