Serendipity, complexity, and loneliness

No sooner (literally)  had I written about the complexity economics of the new book by David Colander and Roland Kupers, [amazon_link id=”0691152098″ target=”_blank” ]Complexity and the Art of Public Policy[/amazon_link], than (in one of the many instances of serendipity in life) another book  on complexity turned up in the post, courtesy of its author, Peter Smith. The book is [amazon_link id=”0957069707″ target=”_blank” ]The Reform of Economics: How the complex systems approach is building a realistic and humane alternative to laissez-faire[/amazon_link].

[amazon_image id=”0957069707″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]The Reform of Economics[/amazon_image]

The book looks like it argues for a more realistic alternative to mainstream economics by actually developing it, using agent-based modelling. In a covering letter, Dr Smith says the intelligent agents: “learn by experience how to respond to market conditions. … They can engage in price exploration, and learn to manage their inventory, plant renewal and cashflow (or go bust), all starting from far-from-equilibrium states.” He also describes his research, and his search for a post-crisis renewal of economics as “a mite lonely.” I think it might be less lonely than he fears.

Slow demise of the economist ex machina

A small number of economists have been interested in complexity theory and related approaches – agent-based modelling, network models – for a long time, and a growing number for a shorter time. Complex models in the technical sense of non-linear dynamic systems, with many inter-connections and feedbacks, can describe economic or financial data well. Their evolution over time is highly sensitive to initial conditions, and they are sometimes characterised by ordered states, a property known as emergence.

There are some very good books about complexity science, such as Mitchell Waldrop’s [amazon_link id=”0140179682″ target=”_blank” ]Complexity[/amazon_link], or Philip Ball’s [amazon_link id=”0099457865″ target=”_blank” ]Critical Mass[/amazon_link]. Albert Laslo Barabasi’s [amazon_link id=”0738206679″ target=”_blank” ]Linked[/amazon_link] sets out the related network approach. There are also quite a few books specifically about complexity in economics. The Santa Fe Institute has long been involved in complexity models, and Brian Arthur and Herb Gintis have applied them to economics. Paul Ormerod’s [amazon_link id=”0571197264″ target=”_blank” ]Butterfly Economics[/amazon_link], [amazon_link id=”057127921X” target=”_blank” ]Why Most Things Fail[/amazon_link] and [amazon_link id=”057127921X” target=”_blank” ]Positive Linking[/amazon_link] are all very accessible introductions to complexity in economics. Eric Beinhocker’s [amazon_link id=”0712676619″ target=”_blank” ]The Origin of Wealth[/amazon_link] is another. Alan Kirman more recently published [amazon_link id=”0415594243″ target=”_blank” ]Complex Economics[/amazon_link].

A new book [amazon_link id=”0691152098″ target=”_blank” ]Complexity and the Art of Public Policy: Solving Society’s Problems from the Bottom Up[/amazon_link] by David Colander and Roland Kupers is therefore not introducing a new area of research. But it is nevertheless doing two very interesting things.

[amazon_image id=”0691152098″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Complexity and the Art of Public Policy: Solving Society’s Problems from the Bottom Up[/amazon_image]

First, it locates complexity models in the context of the history of economic thought, explaining why and how economics turned away from the intuitively complexity-based approach of the classical economists (and the also both Hayek and Keynes ). There is a nice anti-reductionism quotation from Keynes: “Once the complexity of reality is carefully considered, the argument that applied policy concerns can be reduced to economics becomes so unreasonable that only an academic would dare consider it.” Colander and Kupers argue instead for what they describe as ‘activist laissez faire’, an approach which still leaves room for disagreement – as between Keynes and Hayek – but about empirical judgements and tactics rather than completely polarised, mutually exclusive approaches.

The authors link the turn in economics away from messy reality, towards sterile abstraction, to the work of Abba Lerner in the 1930s. They argue that his [amazon_link id=”0678006180″ target=”_blank” ]The Economics of Control[/amazon_link] was one of the founding texts of the viewpoint that came to dominate the discipline, the standard state control economic policy framework. This caught on because it was simple, clear, and cast economists as the experts who could identify what policies were needed to maximise social welfare with their analytically soluble models. State intervention was only needed when laissez faire markets failed – but one could argue that that was almost always. This is the attitude so brilliantly described in James Scott’s [amazon_link id=”0300078153″ target=”_blank” ]Seeing Like A State[/amazon_link]. Thus the stage was set for the dualism between interventionism and free market-ism, between ‘Keynesians’ and monetarists. The account in this book sets the reductionist turn in economics earlier than the conventional wisdom has it – others locate it in the 1940s and 1950s.

[amazon_image id=”0300078153″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed (Yale Agrarian Studies)[/amazon_image]

Aside from the discussion of the history of economic thought, the main contribution of this book is that it discusses the implications of the ‘complexity framework’ for the way we should think about public policy, arguing that it will get us away from the sterility of the markets versus states dualism. Instead, the role of both has to be respected – government in setting the rules and conditions, markets in delivering bottom-up choices in an efficient way. The policy intervention is  itself inside the system.

As the book points out, this is not consistent at all with the standard frame of economics, in which the economist is a deus ex machina calculating the optimal policy and implementing it – a command-and-control framework of thought that has spread far wider than economics to capture all of public policy and even business decision making.This has extracted a high price and I think is certainly at the root of the present dissatisfaction with economics.

The authors argue that the problem in economics itself is mainly with macro and theory, as the applied micro areas of the field have been steadily moving away from assumed rationality, linearity, static equilibrium etc for some decades now – behavioural economics being the obvious example. In 2000, this led Paul David to declare that ‘neoclassical’ economics was dead. The exception, however, is the one bit of economics that all normal people know about because it’s in the news all the time, not least because of the financial crisis and its aftermath. As the authors write: “Issues of morality, the market and the constitutional order should have been central to the policy debate about macroeconomics. They weren’t. The standard frame eliminated them from discussion.” They are wonderfully scathing about modern DSGE macro, a view with which I wholeheartedly agree. “While microeconomics has evolved considerably in the direction of complexity, progress in macro has been very limited.” What students are currently taught in their macro courses is not useful and in fact inconsistent with empirical reality.

Outside economics, in the wider influence the subject and its approach have had on public policy, reductionism still reigns, and probably will until future generations of people who have studied economics have experienced a different kind of curriculum. Colander and Kuper end with a curriculum reform proposal – economics education is a longstanding interest of David Colander, who contributed a chapter to [amazon_link id=”1907994041″ target=”_blank” ]What’s the Use of Economics[/amazon_link]. Role on the roll-out of INET’s CORE curriculum!

However, I think this book is more useful for people in the policy world rather than universities. It could start to chip away at the damaging idea that policy makers are deus ex machina, outside the system (something I spoke about in my Pro Bono lecture The Economist As Outsider), and focus attention once again on the importance of the institutional, cultural and ethical framework within which people make economic decisions.

Virtual serendipity

Serendipitously, the day after writing about [amazon_link id=”0262027259″ target=”_blank” ]Virtual Economies[/amazon_link] by Vili Lehdonvirta and Edward Castronova, another new book by Edward Castronova arrived in the post, [amazon_link id=”B00KMUWRXG” target=”_blank” ]Wildcat Currency: How the Virtual Money Revolution is Transforming the Economy[/amazon_link]. It’s about the convergence of the ‘real’ and the virtual in the domain of money, although of course as money is already largely virtual, this is more about the crowding out of the previously public domain of money by private currencies: “Today anybody can be a central bank.” On a quick glance through, [amazon_link id=”B00KMUWRXG” target=”_blank” ]Wildcat Currency[/amazon_link] looks like an accessible overview of the territory.

[amazon_image id=”B00KMUWRXG” link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Wildcat Currency[/amazon_image]

This is a hot subject of course. In which context , it would be remiss of me not to highlight another excellent recent book about the future of money, Dave Birch’s [amazon_link id=”1907994122″ target=”_blank” ]Identity is the New Money[/amazon_link].

[amazon_image id=”1907994122″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Identity is the New Money (Perspectives)[/amazon_image]

The real and the virtual converge

What are virtual economies for? In their new book, [amazon_link id=”0262027259″ target=”_blank” ]Virtual Economies: Design and Analysis[/amazon_link], Vili Lehdonvirta and Edward Castronova focus on the answer: providing a viable business model for the operators of digital games. “Digital publishers are usually for-profit companies that aim to make money. Their specific approach to making money is providing digital content to consumers. On a very abstract level, their business consists of three processes: creating content, attracting users, and monetizing. Virtual economy design, like every other function in the company, must somehow contribute to these processes.” So the economy-design principles they set out in the rest of the book are intended to serve this profit-making aim.

[amazon_image id=”0262027259″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Virtual Economies: Design and Analysis (Information Policy): Design and Anaysis[/amazon_image]

But of course, as that quotation makes it clear, the same processes applies to digital companies other than those providing online games – they are also the main processes for music, books, newspapers, films, education providers. So the ‘games design’ principles described in the book have some interesting applications to other kinds of business, and it makes this an interesting complement to one of my all-time favourite digital business books, [amazon_link id=”087584863X” target=”_blank” ]Information Rules[/amazon_link] by Carl Shapiro and Hal Varian. There is more exchange and macroeconomics here than in [amazon_link id=”087584863X” target=”_blank” ]Information Rules[/amazon_link] because of the gaming context, but there is a lot of food for thought in this book for anybody in any ‘content’ business.

[amazon_link id=”0262027259″ target=”_blank” ]Virtual Economies[/amazon_link] serves a third function too: it is a terrific introduction to economics. In a clear and straightforward way it covers everything from consumer choice theory to macroeconomic demand management and money; and it combines both the conventional approach as it would be taught today and informed critique of the standard assumptions and approaches. For example, the chapter on consumer choice includes both rational choice and alternatives – bounded rationality, behavioural biases, social psychology. There is a whole chapter on institutions and non-market allocation. The final chapter touches on the role of economic institutions as ends in themselves as well as instruments. It concludes with some thoughts on ‘the end of materialism’: not only are large parts of the economy already virtual, but perhaps future growth will be increasingly virtual? This certainly appeals to me as the author of The Weightless World (pdf)!

Anyway, I could see using this as a textbook for an introductory economics course with the term’s collective task for the students being to set up an online economy. It would be unconventional but I can see it equipping students with a terrific basic understanding of trends in economics and business.

Edward Castronova has almost cornered the market in the economics of games – his previous book was [amazon_link id=”0226096270″ target=”_blank” ]Synthetic Worlds: The Business and Culture of Online Games[/amazon_link]. Vili Lehdonvirta is at the Oxford Internet Institute and has written some fascinating papers. Yannis Varoufakis is the economist for Valve but writes far more about the EU – here is one interesting paper he wrote on digital economies though. Hal Varian is of course at Google now. But this is a subject on which most conventional economists are strangely silent – I guess they think it’s a frivolous subject and haven’t noticed that the real world and the virtual worlds are converging. So hooray for this very interesting new book on the subject, highly recommended.

Making democracy fun

[amazon_link id=”0262026872″ target=”_blank” ]Making Democracy Fun: How Game Design Can Empower Citizens and Transform Politics[/amazon_link] is the title of a new book by Josh Lerner. It looks fascinating. The book describes how to make political participation game-like – from game theory to game practice. The book is practical, giving examples of techniques to use in contexts such as local planning decisions and policy design. The final chapter provides a policy-makers’ toolkit, and ends by recommending the application of the tools to democratic political participation.

[amazon_image id=”0262026872″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Making Democracy Fun: How Game Design Can Empower Citizens and Transform Politics[/amazon_image]

Interestingly, the book advocates games in actual, physical meetings – hence the very local applications such as urban planning. Lerner argues that online games have far less impact – although presumably in any electoral context, participatory games would have to be digital. He writes: “Most enthusiasts of political games … start with digital tools. I instead focus on the basic mechanics of games, through the lens of face-to-face examples. This design know-how can then be applied to digital and non-digital games, and everything in between.”

So, an intriguing, practical book for activists, organisers, planners and local politicians. Without having read it yet, I’m sceptical about the book’s bigger claim that games can rebuild trust in democratic processes (‘transform politics’). And about how citizens’ greater participation through fun would help speedy planning decisions in the public interest when Nimbyism is so rife. I’ll have to read it to find out if games can incorporate the interests of those who can’t afford a home and so are not even participants in the decision-making process. Do they get a seat at the games table?