Guest post on the (changing) state of economics

Bringing About Debate and Change in Economics.

By Peter Smith

The financial crisis has raised serious questions about the validity of mainstream economics and whether it addresses some important aspects of reality. This does suggest that at least some radical changes are needed in the core economic models of ‘how the world really is’. I’d like to suggest that outsiders can have a useful role when change of such a radical kind is needed; at the very least, we may have tools and approaches that economists are not familiar with. History is on my side here: some of Thomas Kuhn’s famous paradigm shifts described in his [amazon_link id=”0226458121″ target=”_blank” ]Structure of Scientific Revolutions[/amazon_link] arose from just this sort of cross-fertilization.

[amazon_image id=”0226458121″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]The Structure of Scientific Revolutions: 50th Anniversary Edition[/amazon_image]

Getting a productive debate going may not be so easy, however, given the mutual suspicion and hostility between (some) external critics and (some) mainstream economists. The latter have perpetrated some appalling examples of arrogance. Lionel Robbins, in [amazon_link id=”0333370392″ target=”_blank” ]the essay[/amazon_link] that defined (mainstream) economics, claimed it was: “A body of generalizations whose substantial accuracy are open to question only by the ignorant or the perverse.” Much more recently, Robert Skidelsky’s description of economics as ‘a branch of logic’ shows that this tradition of disdain for critics is alive and kicking. (Skidelsky seems to hold the mistaken belief that you cannot arrive at erroneous conclusions using logic.)

In the opposite direction, though, external critics perceive a theme (about the need to reduce the size and role of the state) that runs from undergraduate textbooks and teaching, right through to the formulation of public policy. It appears to unify the discipline and all its members around a body of theory that provides politically-convenient support for laissez-faire – despite having a number of serious flaws that have persisted, un-mended, for many decades (such as the lack of any realistic model of how buyers and sellers get to know the ‘true’ price). What is really going on here?

Our critical instinct is to go into even the earliest stages of contact with academic economists eager to trash this set of ideas – totally missing the point that not all economists are tarred with the same brush. If we, the external critics, imply that all economists are engaged in a conspiracy to suppress our criticism, we brand ourselves as ignorant, and thereby lose potential allies within the profession. (I’m using ‘we’ because my home discipline is management – not sure quite where I belong now.)

In reality, there are many senior academics who have long held deep reservations about the power of markets to optimise anything, and do not subscribe to the old easy certainties about laissez-faire. (Curiously, [amazon_link id=”1907994041″ target=”_blank” ]these reservations[/amazon_link] are almost entirely absent from undergraduate teaching and textbooks.) The profession is still deeply-divided, though, and other eminent academics do still adhere to the old certainties. In an article in The Economist, Robert Lucas claimed that the post-2007 crisis should not be taken as evidence of deep-seated flaws in mainstream economics, because the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH) showed that such crises were inherently unforeseeable – this despite the considerable body of evidence against the EMH. (There is a summary of this in Robert Shiller’s [amazon_link id=”0691166269″ target=”_blank” ]Irrational Exuberance[/amazon_link].) At the very least, we are able to see when we are entering a period of great potential instability – the case studies of earlier crises in Paul Krugman’s [amazon_link id=”1846142393″ target=”_blank” ]Return of Depression Economics[/amazon_link] identify some interesting indicators.

[amazon_image id=”0691166269″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Irrational Exuberance[/amazon_image]   [amazon_image id=”1846142393″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]The Return of Depression Economics[/amazon_image]

The profession also includes those who studied economics, years or decades back. They were taught that (mainstream) economics is indeed ‘a body of generalizations whose substantial accuracy are open to question only by the ignorant or the perverse’. A lot of my old colleagues in the major international development organizations belong to this group. With few exceptions, they certainly subscribe to the belief that mainstream economics has got it just about right – as do many economic commentators, notably The Times columnist, Daniel Finkelstein. I am thinking particularly of his encomium (14th Dec 2014) on the late Gary Becker. (Becker was probably the most over-confident advocate of extending mainstream economic principles to cover much of human non-market behaviour.)

Finally, there are politicians who want to use the simple messages about the beneficence of market forces to promote an agenda of ‘rolling back the state’ – some from sincere conviction, some in cynical pursuit of personal or factional interests.

Mainstream economics isn’t a single, monolithic body of experts and expertise. Rather than attacking this mirage, we all – meaning internal and external critics alike – should be thinking about a radical review of the mainstream paradigm, and seeking more realistic alternatives. (One thing that my particular school of outsiders can contribute is skills and approaches for managing that process.) That, however, is a much bigger story, one for another day.

Peter blogs as EconomicsEye. Since starting out in the natural sciences, he has worked in project management, and the management of R&D and innovation.

Economics for the curious

Each August there’s a meeting in Lindau of economics (and other) Nobel laureates.* I’ve never attended but have just been looking at the book of essays for young economists written by the participants in the conference, [amazon_link id=”1137383585″ target=”_blank” ]Economics for the Curious[/amazon_link] edited by Robert Solow with Janice Murray. There’s an obviously impressive list of contributors, whose talks cover subjects ranging from natural resource sustainability (Robert Solow) to structural change in the global economy (Mike Spence, who taught me a graduate micro course once upon a time) to the role of transactions costs in the social sciences (Oliver Williamson) and the character of economics (Vernon Smith).

[amazon_image id=”1137383585″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Economics for the Curious: Inside the Minds of 12 Nobel Laureates[/amazon_image]

The essays (the ones I’ve read) are very accessible and non-technical. Solow’s essay on applying economic principles to renewable and non-renewable resources is a model of clarity that could be set for undergraduates. Williamson’s essay on transactions cost economics is fascinating. He insists on the importance of interdisciplinarity – I hadn’t known he started out an engineer and came to economics via business. He usefully describes Coase’s famous 1960 paper, The Problem of Social Cost (pdf), the origin of modern institutional economics, as an exercise in reductio ad absurdum – what happens when you push the logic of zero transactions costs to its conclusion? He usefully captures Coase’s stricture against ‘blackboard economics’ by explaining the need for comparing any activity being analysed, not to an abstract ideal of efficiency, but to a realistic alternative. He ends with advice to students to take elective courses in any filed that interests them. “Try it. You may like it.”

I’ll now finish reading the essays, but my impression is that it’s a little book which is perfectly pitched for undergraduates or sixth formers, and is currently only just over £10 on Amazon.

 

 

 

* I know it isn’t a ‘real’ Nobel, ok?

The non-existent shark

Self-help books aren’t my cup of tea, so I’ve only really paged through It’s [amazon_link id=”1250042038″ target=”_blank” ]Not About the Shark: How to Solve Unsolvable Problems[/amazon_link] by David Niven. The title comes from Steven Spielberg’s decision to make Jaws with very few shots of the shark, because the expensive mechanical shark he’d had built didn’t work. It turned out to be more menacing with an imagined shark. That’s the gist of the book – re-interpreting problems as a changed environment rather than an immovable object. There are some other nice anecdotes. It’s a quick, light plane or train read if you like this kind of book. I didn’t spot anything that really tells you how to exercise your imagination in Spielberg-style creative ways.

[amazon_image id=”1250042038″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]It’s Not about the Shark: How to Solve Unsolvable Problems[/amazon_image]

Which economists should be more influential?

Chris Dillow over at Stumbling and Mumbling has responded to The Economist’s controversial list of the world’s most influential economists with a post saying complexity economics should be more influential. I agree with him. But he set me thinking about which other economists ought to have featured in the list.

One glaring feature of the ranking is the complete absence of women. It excludes current (but not former) central bankers, so Janet Yellen doesn’t feature. Nor does Christine Lagarde – a lawyer, true, but not all the people on the list are economists anyway. There are other highly influential women who surely ought to have featured, such as [amazon_link id=”1586487981″ target=”_blank” ]Esther Duflo[/amazon_link], [amazon_link id=”0674035305″ target=”_blank” ]Claudia Goldin[/amazon_link], [amazon_link id=”0857282522″ target=”_blank” ]Mariana Mazzucato[/amazon_link], doing work that has been much discussed in the publications and blogs I look at. It’s a very Anglo-American list too, as it is about the English language blogosphere.

[amazon_image id=”B0092I0M0Y” link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Poor Economics A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty by Duflo, Esther ( Author ) ON Jun-09-2011, Hardback[/amazon_image]  [amazon_image id=”0674035305″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Race between Education and Technology[/amazon_image] [amazon_image id=”0857282522″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]The Entrepreneurial State: Debunking Public vs. Private Sector Myths (Anthem Other Canon Economics)[/amazon_image]

The other striking thing is that the list only contains two sub-disciplines, behavioural economics and macro. Important, but my goodness there is so much more to economics.

So my nomination for economists who ought to have been included are all those applied micro people working on public policy issues. They are often attached to institutes and work collaboratively. It only takes a quick glance at the research publications issued by the IFS, CMPO, CEP, CEPR, NIESR in the UK, or the NBER or TSE – or many, many other groups in many countries – to see what an impressive amount of empirical economic evidence is accumulating. I guess it isn’t so visible because it is dispersed among different questions – everything from my University of Manchester colleague Rachel Griffith‘s work on the causes of obesity to Marc Ivaldi on competition policy in the telecoms and technology sectors  to Costas Meghir and colleagues on the inter-generational returns to women’s education. Nor does it make the headlines often, as the public debate is so macro-dominated.

Which is a handy way of segueing into saying I am now on the roster of contributors to the FT’s new blog The Exchange, and have a post there today about how we should be thinking about infrastructure investment. I’ll be writing about applied micro and policy issues.