Policy pickles redux

History repeats itself, with variations; as the famous Reinhart and Rogoff book on sovereign debt crises argues, [amazon_link id=”0691152640″ target=”_blank” ]This Time is Different[/amazon_link] – not! I’ve just been reading a fascinating book by Bill Allen on UK macro policy history, [amazon_link id=”113738381X” target=”_blank” ]Monetary Policy and Financial Repression in Britain, 1951-59[/amazon_link]. The 1950s were preceded by a period remarkably like today’s context in important ways. The Bank rate – the key policy rate of the period – had been kept at 2% for nearly two decades, to combat the Depression, finance the war, and keep the economy growing in the post-war years. With a new government in 1951, monetary policy was ‘reactivated’.

[amazon_image id=”113738381X” link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Monetary Policy and Financial Repression in Britain, 1951 – 59 (Palgrave Studies in Economic History Series)[/amazon_image]

The author – formerly a senior Bank of England director and now at Cass Business School – argues that the 1950s have highly relevant lessons for today. The Bank’s key rate has been at 0.5% for more than five years and will stay there for some time longer. With short-term government debt outstanding amounting to £342bn at the time he wrote (just over 20% of GDP), “This means that any increase in short-term interest rates would entail an immediate and substantial increase in government expenditure.” Yet, he continues, it is inconceivable that interest rates can stay so low for ever. The only way is up.

What possible paths are there out of this situation? Either higher interest rates will lead to a big increase in the fiscal deficit or (much) more austerity; or nominal GDP will have to rise substantially either via real growth or higher inflation to reduce the fiscal impact of higher interest rates; or banks will have to be forced to bear some of the cost of rising interest rates – as in the 1950s – by a requirement to hold very large non-interest bearing deposits at the Bank of England. The first option is unappealing, the second unlikely given present economic trends. “One fine day there will have to be a new reactivation of monetary policy, and the authorities will have to manage exactly the same problem that faced their predecessors.”

There are of course some very important differences between now and the 1950s, including the fact that the amount of private debt outstanding now is so much greater (141% of GDP vs 16% of GDP in 1951, the much lower liquidity ratios of banks now). Still, the parallels make this history extremely interesting. The bulk of the book consists of a chronological account of monetary policy and description of the techniques used and decisions made over the decade. The final chapters cover four themes: monetary policy tools, financial repression, power and influence, and an overall assessment of the monetary policy chosen.

The power and influence chapter is especially interesting. This was long before Bank of England independence so the Chancellor of the Exchequer took the policy decisions and was in principle answerable to the House of Commons. In practice, secrecy prevailed, and there was almost no communication about policy – quite a contrast to today’s situation of ample, and perhaps even excessive to the point of confusion, communication. The book places the blame for the prevailing secrecy on the dire state of Britain’s financial problems both in the 1930s and again after the war. “Formal post-war default by the UK would have been technically possible but politically poisonous.” Commentators on policy had to apply guesswork to figure out what the Bank of England had already done, never mind what its future actions might be – the book uses archive material to fill in the blanks.

One result was that academic discussions diverged from practice, a damaging divorce. For those who understood the institutional reality of money and those who developed theories about monetary policy on the whole stopped speaking to each other – something we arguably paid the price for in the recent crisis, by which time the non-institutionally grounded theories had reversed themselves into central bank thinking too. (I find the institutional detail explained in this book far more interesting than the abstractions of macroeconomic models, I must say. It brought back to me memories of reading parts of the Radcliffe Committee Report in my undergraduate days, and being intrigued by the practicalities of monetary policy – an interest thoroughly destroyed by subsequent exposure to real business cycle theories and representative agent models.)

My sole criticism of this fascinating account of the reality of a decisive decade in UK monetary history is that it’s priced for institutional libraries (£70); but anybody at all interested in how we might find a way out of the present policy pickle would do well to borrow a copy.

All the way from the Stone Age and back again?

There’s a growing genre of books, the long sweep of human history from a social science perspective. The ur-text must be Jacob Bronowski’s [amazon_link id=”1849901155″ target=”_blank” ]The Ascent of Man[/amazon_link] (the DVD of the series is still available and, I think, still fascinating despite being so old-fashioned.) I suppose the recent wave started with Jared Diamond’s [amazon_link id=”0099302780″ target=”_blank” ]Guns, Germs and Steel[/amazon_link] (1997), and more conventional economic histories such as David Landes in the [amazon_link id=”0349111669″ target=”_blank” ]Wealth and Poverty of Nations[/amazon_link] (1998). More recent contributions have come from Ian Morris, with [amazon_link id=”1846682088″ target=”_blank” ]Why the West Rules – For Now[/amazon_link] (2011) and [amazon_link id=”0691155682″ target=”_blank” ]The Measure of Civilization[/amazon_link] (2013), and Diamond again with [amazon_link id=”0241958687″ target=”_blank” ]Collapse[/amazon_link] (2005).

[amazon_image id=”0563104988″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]The Ascent of Man[/amazon_image]

The latest is Yuval Noah Harari’s [amazon_link id=”1846558239″ target=”_blank” ]Sapiens: A Brief History of Humankind[/amazon_link], just published in the UK with a lot of publicity razzmatazz. I’ve not read it, just this extract in The Guardian. It touches on how we measure progress, and is happiness a better aim than GDP. It isn’t entirely clear to me what the conclusion is – that we were happier in the Stone Age? To which the answer is surely the economist’s sceptical revealed preference argument: see how many voters want to revert to a hunter-gatherer society. Or is Harari instead arguing for giving evolution a bit of a boost?

“Humans are not adapted by evolution to experience constant pleasure, so ice‑cream and smartphone games will not do. If that is what humankind nevertheless wants, it will be necessary to re-engineer our bodies and minds. We are working on it.”

[amazon_image id=”1846558239″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Sapiens: A Brief History of Humankind[/amazon_image]

The education of an economist

In the Financial Times this morning Deirdre McCloskey has a tantalising curtain-raiser for her forthcoming book, Bourgeois Equality: How Betterment Became Ethical, 1600-1848, and Then Suspect. Her argument is that it isn’t the accumulation of capital but rather innovation that is the engine of wealth, collective and individual:

“Taxing the rich, or capital, does not help the poor. It can throw a spanner into the mightiest engine for lifting up those below us, arising from a new equality, not of material worth but of liberty and dignity. Gini coefficients are not what matter; the Great Enrichment is.”

McCloskey has been on an anti-Piketty tour – see for example this by Evan Davis in The Spectator, and McCloskey herself speaking recently to the IEA. It’s intriguing that two of the economists most admired by progressive, anti-free-market, reforming economics people – McCloskey and Piketty – are in such disagreement.

The forthcoming book is the final volume in McCloskey’s trilogy, The Bourgeois Era, preceded by Vols 1 [amazon_link id=”0226556646″ target=”_blank” ]The Bourgeois Virtues: Ethics for an Age of Commerce[/amazon_link] and 2 [amazon_link id=”0226556743″ target=”_blank” ]Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t Explain the Modern World[/amazon_link] (I reviewed the latter for the New Statesman.)

[amazon_image id=”0226556743″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Bourgeois Dignity: Why Economics Can’t Explain the Modern World[/amazon_image]

Occasionally I might disagree with Prof McCloskey, but I love her books. One of my all-time favourites is [amazon_link id=”0472067443″ target=”_blank” ]How to Be Human (though an economist)[/amazon_link] and of course her book with Stephen Zilliak, [amazon_link id=”0472050079″ target=”_blank” ]The Cult of Statistical Significance: How the Standard Error Costs Us Jobs, Justice, and Lives[/amazon_link].

[amazon_image id=”0472067443″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]How to Be Human: Through an Economist[/amazon_image]   [amazon_image id=”0472050079″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]The Cult of Statistical Significance: How the Standard Error Costs Us Jobs, Justice, and Lives (Economics, Cognition & Society)[/amazon_image]

I love even more the reading lists for her courses. Just look at the instructions for Economics 326: The History of Economic Thought, 2006, for example, or the graduate seminar Economics 263, or Economics for Humanists. It’s clear one would have to really work, but who wouldn’t want to be taught economics like this?

Order and disorder

I’ve been looking for the first time in some years at Douglass North’s short book [amazon_link id=”0691145954″ target=”_blank” ]Understanding the Process of Economic Change[/amazon_link]. North won his Nobel for the application of institutional economics to economic history, or in other words at the role played in the shaping of institutions and hence events by transactions costs and property rights.

This book is about how different societies arrive at their set of institutions. In particular, what enabled the historically rare success of the United States in the 20th century in establishing an orderly and thriving society, able to adapt even in the face of conflicts and technological change? And why has this kind of success been so rare in history, given that order seems clearly preferable to disorder?

[amazon_image id=”0691145954″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Understanding the Process of Economic Change (The Princeton Economic History of the Western World)[/amazon_image]

His answer lies in the beliefs members of a society hold, especially their beliefs in the legitimacy of their economic and political institutions. The book identifies four conditions for a society to produce order in the face of change. They are:

– citizens have rights that imply limits to the behaviour of officials and politicians;

– there is a constitutional framework that limits the decision-making power of the government;

– property and personal rights are well-defined and legally protected;

– the state credibly commits to upholding these rights, protecting citizens against expropriation by public officials.

This isn’t dissimilar to the conditions set out by Acemoglu and Robinson in [amazon_link id=”1846684307″ target=”_blank” ]Why Nations Fail[/amazon_link] for institutions to be ‘non-extractive’ – and indeed, their book cites North’s work quite extensively.

[amazon_image id=”1846684307″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty[/amazon_image]

Much of North’s focus here is on how to improve the institutional framework in developing economies, but his criteria are clearly more general. But he ends with a word about the United States: “All societies throughout history have eventually decayed and disappeared. … There is no guarantee that the [US’s] flexible, adaptively efficient institutional structure will persist in the ever more complex novel world we are creating.” I wouldn’t want to forecast anything, but it isn’t obvious at present that order has the upper hand over disorder.

Your economic history suggestions collated

A few days ago I asked, what economic history do economists need to know? Since then, I’ve thought of a few extra myself – although the list below barely still scratches the surface! Keep the ideas coming.

[amazon_link id=”0691143277″ target=”_blank” ]Power and Plenty[/amazon_link], Ronald Findlay and Kevin O’Rourke

[amazon_image id=”0691143277″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World Economy in the Second Millennium (The Princeton Economic History of the Western World)[/amazon_image]

[amazon_link id=”0226014746″ target=”_blank” ]The Institutional Revolution[/amazon_link], Douglas Allen

[amazon_link id=”0471295639″ target=”_blank” ]Against the Gods: The remarkable story of risk[/amazon_link], Peter Bernstein

[amazon_link id=”1847376460″ target=”_blank” ]The Prize: the epic quest for power, oil and money[/amazon_link], Daniel Yergin

[amazon_link id=”0140258264″ target=”_blank” ]Accidental Empires[/amazon_link], Robert Cringely

[amazon_image id=”0140258264″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Accidental Empires: How the Boys of Silicon Valley Make Their Millions, Battle Foreign Competition and Still Can’t Get a Date[/amazon_image]

Below, I’ve collated some of the additional suggestions other people have made.

Tom Clark, author of [amazon_link id=”0300203772″ target=”_blank” ]Hard Times: The Divisive Toll of the Economic Slump[/amazon_link], emailed: “Robert Shiller’s [amazon_link id=”0691123357″ target=”_blank” ]Irrational Exuberance[/amazon_link]. Arguably a bit old now, but still teaches you how to make sense of what’s going on in financial markets today in the light of decades of experience. Barry Eichengreen’s [amazon_link id=”0691139377″ target=”_blank” ]Globalising Capital[/amazon_link], which does the whole history of the global monetary system v elegantly in a couple of hundred pages. The classic [amazon_link id=”0765809443″ target=”_blank” ]Marienthal study[/amazon_link] of the effect of unemployment (which I read in full for Hard Times, and is a powerful as well as a nice quick read).” He also suggested Galbraith’s [amazon_link id=”014103825X” target=”_blank” ]The Great Crash 1929[/amazon_link].

[amazon_image id=”0691139377″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ][amazon_image id=”0691139377″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System (Second Edition)[/amazon_image]

[amazon_image id=”0765809443″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]Marienthal (Ppr): The Sociography of an Unemployed Community[/amazon_image]

Robotenomics: “I’d recommend considering [amazon_link id=”B00D0DM4V2″ target=”_blank” ]Prophet of Innovation: Joseph Schumpeter and Creative Destruction[/amazon_link] by Thomas McCraw, and [amazon_link id=”1843763311″ target=”_blank” ]Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital[/amazon_link] by Carlota Perez.”

Christopher May: Karl Polanyi’s classic [amazon_link id=”080705643X” target=”_blank” ]The Great Transformation[/amazon_link]

Brian Labatte: A. Chandler, [amazon_link id=”1614275084″ target=”_blank” ]Strategy and Structure[/amazon_link]; A. Sloan, [amazon_link id=”0385042353″ target=”_blank” ]My Years with General Motors[/amazon_link].

[amazon_image id=”0385042353″ link=”true” target=”_blank” size=”medium” ]My Years with General Motors[/amazon_image]

Steven Clarke: “I’m currently reading David Landes [amazon_link id=”052153402X” target=”_blank” ]The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present[/amazon_link] and would thoroughly recommend it.”

Ronald Grey: [amazon_link id=”0230365353″ target=”_blank” ]Manias, Panics, and. Crashes. A History of Financial Crises[/amazon_link] by Charles Kindleberger

Duncan Green: Anything and everything by Ha-Joon Chang (from [amazon_link id=”1843310279″ target=”_blank” ]Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective[/amazon_link] onwards) and Dani Rodrik ([amazon_link id=”0691141177″ target=”_blank” ]One Economics, Many Recipes[/amazon_link]).

Merjin Knibbe: [amazon_link id=”0307962431″ target=”_blank” ]Money, the unauthorized biography[/amazon_link]

Martin Chick tweeted:

Attlee8
@diane1859 My first year’s in British EH begin with Keynes, Essays In Persuasion; Meade Intelligent Radical’s Guide to Economy;
14/07/2014 07:52